Regional Agreements and International Law

AuthorXu Qian
PositionHundred Talents Program Fellow, Guanghua Law School of Zhejiang University
Pages35-53
35
Unit 3: Regional Agreements and International Law1
Moderator: Xu Qian (Hundred Talents Program Fellow, Guanghua Law School of
Zhejiang University)
Wei Shen (Professor, KoGuan School of Law at Shanghai Jiaotong University)
Topic: Reflections on Multilateralism and Regionalism
Hello, everyone!
My topic today is “Reflections on Multilateralism and Regionalism”, but will focus
more on minilateralism, so “Reflections on minilateralism and regionalism” might be a
more reasonable title. There are many views on multilateralism and minilateralism. For
example, “Multilateralism is the practice of coordinating national policies among three or
more countries by means of special arrangements or institutions.” Also, “multilateralism
with fewer parties is minilateralism”. There is a view that during the formation of the
Bretton Woods System, the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank’s special
majority voting mechanism itself is a kind of minilateralism. There are also views that
minilateralism is highly effective and is a way for a small number of countries to solve a
certain type of problems.
It is worth noting: minilateralism is not a concept of right or wrong, but a concept of
efficiency.
Chinese scholars seem to be less agreeable with the concept of minilateralism,
believing that multilateralism refers to real multilateralism. The minilateralism outside of
multilateralism is a pseudo-multilateralism, a relatively fake multilateralism.
There are also views that, in addition to quantity, minilateralism is also ad hoc and
issue-oriented; distinguishing multilateralism from minilateralism is not a simple
calculation of quantity, but also includes the type of organizational relationship.
Furthermore, how does minilateralism differ from multilateralism? Mainly, the
participating subjects are limited to specific regions and countries of the Commonwealth.
Minilateralism is exclusive, elitism, procedural injustice, and self-serving.
Chris Brummer is one of the scholars who have recently systematically studied
minilateralism in mainstream American law schools. He published a book titled
“Minilateralism” by Cambridge University Press in 2014. He believes that the dominance
of multilateral trade institutions has been broken, and minilateralism has exclusive
characteristics; this exclusive characteristic has had a relatively large impact on the
cooperation mechanism of multilateralism. He also hopes the United States will continue
the path of minilateralism to promote a trade and investment agenda that will be eventually
beneficial to the United States.
Willian T. Tow pointed out that minilateralism is becoming an increasingly prominent
trend in geopolitics.
At least there is some overlap between multilateralism and regionalism. If they are
two circles, they have intersections and differences. Accordingly, I make some distinctions.
1 This Unit is translated by Qianhan Qian (East China University of Political Science and Law) and Xiaofu
Li (Associate Editor of FLIA Review). The translation has been modified and confirmed by the speakers.
36
Today I focus on the operandi of the United States in the practice of minilateralism
from the Donald Trump administration to the Joseph Biden administration. In fact, the
Donald Trump administration is evidently promoting minilateralism. For example, the
United States has withdrawn from some multilateral agreements, and at the same time, is
leading and dominating new small-scale trade agreements, including the United States-
Mexico-Canada Agreement (USMCA) and those between the United States and Japan, the
United States and Singapore, the United States and Europe, the United States and South
Korea.
The Joseph Biden administration does not follow the same approaches as the Donald
Trump administration, but applies a new term “New Internationalism”, for example, the
four member states of the Pacific Alliance, the Five Eyes, the three-nation mechanism of
the United States, Australia and the United Kingdom. To a certain extent, these also belong
to minilateralism, as a kind of small groupism, or pseudo-multilateralism criticized by
Chinese scholars.
In my opinion, when criticizing the ideologicalization of international trade rules by
the United States, Chinese scholars may view the minilateralism practice of the United
States through an ideological lens or “moral glasses”. But whether multilateralism has 5, 6,
or 164 members as the World Trade Organization, it does not matter whether it is “fake” or
“true”, as the idea of minilateralism is to promote multilateralism that is beneficial to
themselves.
What I will say next is the connotation and theoretical framework of US-orientated
minilateralism.
There is an interesting issue in international economic law —the mathematical
problem of “how many sides are appropriate” for international economic and trade
agreements. From the concept itself, “few” and “small” themselves contain the meaning
that the number of participating parties in the global multilateral system is reduced,
narrowed, and limited, which itself is a dynamic change. It itself does not have a scientific
and quantitative definition. For example, 2, 3, 4, and 5 are all theoretically possible.
The multilateralism that international law scholars talk about is actually a WTO-
centered multilateralism. There is a problem with this multilateralism the collective
action dilemma, what is also called the efficiency of collective action. The core feature of
minilateralism is to make up for efficiency problems or to solve this efficiency problem.
Therefore, Miles Kahler argues that the “majority” (involving multiple parties) is an
insurmountable obstacle to collective activity, and this is a reality. For example, when it
comes to advancing the Silk Road Economic Belt and the 21st-Century Maritime Silk Road,
there is also a collective action dilemma: China is leading, and other countries are
cooperating, but they are not promoting the initiative as hard as China. This is a clearer
example of the collective action dilemma.
What are the main goals of minilateralism? One goal is to expand rules. Minilateralism
is to establish some new rules in a small scope, but its purpose is to expand these rules,
resulting in rule spillovers, which play a role in the extension of these rules. Organizations
or other countries can also absorb such rules.
Another goal is to achieve national interests —be it multilateralism or globalization.
In the process of promoting multilateralism or participating in multilateralism, the purpose
of a country is to achieve national interests, such as promoting national development,
improving people’s living standards, and promoting scientific and technological progress.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT