The Independent Director System in China: Weaknesses, Dilemmas, and Potential Silver Linings

AuthorSang Yop Kang
Pages152-185
152 TSINGHUA CHINA LAW REVIEW [Vol. 9:151
THE INDEPENDENT DIRECTOR SYSTEM IN CHINA:
WEAKNESSES, DILEMMAS, AND POTENTIAL SILVER
LININGS*
Sang Yop Kang
Abstract
The independent director system in C hina has many weaknesses.
Independent directors might not be truly independe nt, and they are
not always equipped with the necessary information and expertise.
The controlling shareholder ownership aggravates problems of the
independent director system. Particularly, it is highly likely that the
system based on rubber-stamp directors is used to justify corporate
policies and transactions in favor of controlling shareholders.
Nonetheless, independent directors in China can bring positive
effects to society. Some tainted proposals are screened out before
submission by corporate insiders to a formal board meeting since
independent directors sometimes raise objections during informal
sessions or private conversations (independent directors’ “direct
deterrence”). Controlling shareholders, due to the concern of
revealing negative information to a capital market and enforc ement
agencies, would not fully demand independent directors to approve
egregious transactions (a controlling shareholders self-
censorship”). In addition, regula tions on the business role of
individuals with government/party or education experien ce should
be carefully reviewed. On the one hand, these regulations can
facilitate anti-corruption campaigns that the Chinese government
currently pursues. On the other hand, there is no guarantee that
alternative groups are more capable, independent, and ethical than
the group with government/party or education al experience.
I. INTRODUCTION
Corporate governance scholars, economists, policy-makers, and
courts generally consider the independent director institution as a
main solution to corporate governance problems.1 After the Enron
* This article is based on an earlier draft that I presented in a conference held at Tsinghua University
School of Law in Beijing on November 1, 2015. Most of all, I thank my mentors, Professors Merritt
Fox, Jeffrey Gordon, Curtis Milhaupt, Katharina Pistor, and Richard Brooks at Columbia Law School
and Jesse Fried at Harvard Law School, for their support. My thanks should go to participants of the
conference at Tsinghua University School of Law. For their valuable comments, I thank particularly
Professors Merritt Fox at Columbia Law School and Xin Tang and Simin Gao at Tsinghua University
School of Law. In addition, I thank Dean Philip McConnaughay, Vice Dean Emeritus Stephen Yandle,
Associate Dean Colleen Toomey, and my colleagues at Peking University School of Transnational Law,
Vice Chancellor Jeffrey Lehman at New York University Shanghai Campus, for their advice and moral
support. Also, I thank Tong Ling, Biyu Wang, Huizi Wu, Ziyan Yuan, Dongtian Zhang, and Liusheng
Zhu, for their assistance. Last but not least, I thank my wife, parents, parents-in-law, and brother for
their endless support for me.
1 See, e.g., Sanjai Bhagat & Bernard Black, The Non-Correlation Between Board Independence and
Long-Term Firm Performance, 27 J. CORP. L. 231, 232 (2002) (“[T]he conventional wisdom [is] that
2017] THE INDEPENDENT DIRECTOR SYSTEM IN CHINA 153
debacle, the role of independent directors was reinforced in the
United States.2 In the late 1990s, Korea adopted the outside director
system (which is functionally similar to the independent director
system) as a corporate governance reform in response to the Asian
financial crisis. China also joined this trend: in 2001, the China
Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC) issued the “Guidance
Opinion on Establishing the Independent Director System”
(hereinafter Guidance Opinion), which required the independent
director system in listed companies.3
The independent director system, however, has many weaknesses.
Most of all, there is no clear definition of or objective standard for
the adjective “independent”: the title “independent director” does not
guarantee the independence of directors. In addition, independent
directors, who work on a part-time basis, often do not receive enough
information from the corporation they direct. Also, critics maintain
that independent directors—even if they are truly independent—
often lack expertise, and face time constraints in understanding
significant corporate business policies. Moreover, empirical studies
do not show a significant correlation between the presence of
independent directors and a corporations performance.4 Even worse,
it is possible that corporate insiders—either management or
controlling shareholders—abuse the independent director system by
using it as a defense mechanism for transactions and policies that
they pursue: to the outside world (including markets in general, the
enforcement agencies, and the court), a corporation’s transactions
and policies appear to be “justified” by the advice and monitoring
process of independent directors, even when they are not truly
independent. Furthermore, independent directors have an incentive
not to lose additional compensation opportunities, which might be
significant. Accordingly, independent directors are likely to follow
corporate insiders, who are influential when recommending,
nominating, and electing directors.
Based on the overview of the weaknesses of the independent
director system, this article develops in-depth analyses of these
the board’s principal task is to monitor management, and only indep endent directors can be effective
monitors.”).
2 Setting the Rules, THE ECONOMIST (Jan. 29, 2003), http://www.economist.com/node/1558898 (“Listed
companies are now required to have a majority of independent (non-executive) directors on their
boards. . . . The board’s all-important compensation, nominating and audit committees are to be
composed entirely of non-executives[.]”).
3 Guanyu zai Shangshi Gongsi Jianli Duli Dongshi Zhidu de Zhidao Yijian (关于在上市公司建立独立
董事制度的指导意见) [Guidance Opinion on Establishing Independent Director System in Listed
Companies] (promulgated by China Sec. Reg. Comm’n, Aug. 16, 2001, effective Aug. 16, 2001)
(Chinalawinfo) [hereinafter Guidance Opinion].
4 See infra Part III. C. Some studies even indicate a negative correlation between the presence of
independent directors and a corporation’s performance. Id.
154 TSINGHUA CHINA LAW REVIEW [Vol. 9:151
issues in the context of Chinese corporate governance practice. For
instance, it is probable that the controlling shareholder ownership,
which most corporations in China are based on, could aggravate the
problems associated with the independent director system. This is
because a controlling shareholder—unlike a CEO in a widely-held
corporation—exercises direct control backed by her/his majority of
voting rights and influence on virtually all corporate policies
including recommendation, nomination, election, and renewal of
independent directors.
Based on the reputational mechanism, in theory,
incentive/efficiency problems of independent directors can be cured.
In jurisdictions with controlling shareholder ownership (including
China), however, it is highly likely that the main audience in the
reputation market that independent directors consider is not public
investors in a capital market, but controlling shareholders.5 Thus, the
mechanism of invisible hands via word-of-mouth would not work
well. Since social networks in China are cumulatively connected in a
complicated matrix through regional, educational and other
backgrounds, the “bad” reputation of an independent director—i.e.,
the reputation that the independent director is truly independent—
will easily spread in the business community. Accordingly,
controlling shareholders, who in practice have the power to elect
independent directors, screen out truly independent directors from
their list. If the trend is strong enough, only compliant independent
directors will remain in the market, which will create a situation
analogous to “adverse selection.”6
According to a recent study, independent directors in Chinese
corporations issued only 0.9% of dissent opinions (including
abstention as well as overt disagreement) in board meetings.7 Such a
high approval rate (99.1%) strongly indicates that independent
directors in China are acting as rubber stamps for controlling
shareholders and corporate insiders. It is worth noting, however, that
what the study examined was only the opinions of independent
directors in official board meetings.
More specifically, the 99.1% approval rate does not reflect two
important processes, wherein the institution of independent
directors—directly or indirectly—can screen out undesirable
5 See infra Part IV. A.
6 Originally, “adverse selection” in a market (e.g., a used car market) is explained as follows: “because
the potential sellers know more about the quality of what they are selling than the potential buyers, they
have an incentive to select the worst things to sell.” PAUL KRUGMAN & ROBIN WELLS,
MICROECONOMICS 560 (2nd ed. 2009).
7 Juan Ma & Tarun Khanna, Independent Directors’ Dissent on Boards: Evidence from Listed
Companies in China, (Harv. Bus. Sch. Working Paper No. 13-089, Oct. 24, 2013) at 11. For a further
explanation of this study, see infra Part III. E. 2.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT